Enigma of Indian Inflation

Through this article, we’ll discuss today the much debated mystery of inflation and will try to seek the possible solution.

Most of the debates revolve around the theory that there is a trade-off between growth and inflation. This theory has its roots in conventional economic ideologies.

On the other hand, now a days, there are people those are the proponent of the idea that there is no tradeoff between growth and inflation.

Let’s have a look on these thoughts one by one.

First we’ll delve into the thoughts of old school which says that there is a trade-off between growth and inflation. Here are some thoughts from the Executive Director, RBI, Mr. Deepak Mohanty:

The conventional view
India is a moderate inflation country. In the eight year period from 2000 to 2007, the world inflation averaged 3.9% per annum. Even the emerging and developing economies (EDEs) which traditionally had very high inflation showed an average annual inflation at 6.7%. India’s inflation performance was even better at 5.2 % as measured by WPI and 4.6% measured by the consumer price index (CPI-IW).

In 2008 the global financial crisis struck following which inflation rose sharply both in advanced countries and EDEs as commodity and oil prices rebounded ahead of a sharp “V” shaped recovery. Thereafter, inflation rate moderated both in advanced economies and EDEs. In India too the inflation rate rose from 4.7% in 2007-08 to 8.1% in 2008-09 and fell to 3.8% in 2009-10, however, it backed up and stayed in double digits during 2010-11 and 2011-12 before showing some moderation in 2012-13. Given India’s good track record of inflation management, the persistence of elevated inflation for over two years is apparently puzzling.

Deceleration of growth and emergence of a significant negative output gap has failed to contain inflation. It is understandable if inflation goes up in an environment of accelerating economic growth. There could be a situation when the real economy is growing above its potential growth that could trigger inflation what economists call an overheating situation.

During a boom, economic activity may for a time rise above this potential level and the output gap becomes positive. During economic slowdown, the economy drops below its potential level and the output gap is negative. Economic theory puts a lot of emphasis on understanding the relationship between output gap and inflation. A negative output gap implies a slack in the economy and hence a downward pressure on inflation. So, India’s current low growth-high inflation dynamics has been in contrast to this conventional economic theory. Real GDP growth has moderated significantly below its potential. Yet inflation did not cool off.

Reserve Bank raised its policy repo rate 13 times between March 2010 and October 2011 by a cumulative 375 basis points. The policy repo rate increased from a low of 4.75 % to 8.5 %. Still it did not help contain inflation. Interest rate is a blunt instrument. It first slows growth and then inflation. But the growth slowdown has not been commensurate with inflation control.

With the persistence of near double-digit inflation in 2010 and 2011, the medium to long-term inflation expectations in the economy have risen, underscoring the role of higher food prices in expectations formation. If inflation is expected to be persistently high, workers bargain for higher nominal wages to protect their real income. This creates a pressure on firms’ costs and they may in turn increase prices to maintain their profits.

Only in an environment of price stability, a step up in investment accompanied by productivity improvements could bolster potential growth. Even when the supply side factors dominate the inflationary pressures, given the risks of spillover into a wider inflationary process, there is need for policy response. While monetary policy action addresses the risk of unhinging of inflation expectations, attending to the structural supply constraints becomes important to ensure that these do not become a binding constraint in the long-run, making the task of inflation management more difficult. By ensuring a low and stable inflation, the Reserve Bank could best contribute to social welfare. (Excerpts from the speech delivered on January 31st 2013).

So, here is the fact that despite raising interest rates progressively RBI failed to put a check on inflation and moreover puzzled by intrigue behaviour of it being high contrary to the low growth rate. At last, Mr. Mohanty opined on the supply side constraints for it being the culprit behind current high inflation.

Now let’s have a look on the other side of the story and see the perspective of opponent of above-mentioned conventional theory, who says that there is no trade-off between growth and inflation. Here are the views of eminent economist Mr. Ajay Shah, Professor, National Institute for Public Finance and Policy:

The counter-view
All of us are aware of India’s inflation crisis. It is very disappointing, how we lost our grip on stable 4-5% inflation which was prevailing earlier. From February 2006 onwards, in every single month, the y-o-y CPI-IW inflation has exceeded the upper bound of 5%.

We also agree that there is something insidious when 10% inflation effectively steals 10% of the value of my wallet or fixed income investments. In India, however, we often hear the argument “Yes, this is bad, but if high inflation is the way to get to high GDP growth, let’s get on with it”. It is, then, important to ask: Why is low inflation valuable?

Nominal contracting is very important
Complex organisation of economic life involves myriad written and unwritten contracts involving households and firms. The vast majority of these contracts are written in nominal terms, i.e. in rupee values that are not adjusted for inflation.

Inflation is an acid that corrodes all nominal contracts. Two people may have agreed on a contract two years ago at Rs.100, but that contract is thrown out of whack because of 10% inflation per annum. That contract has to be renegotiated. Bigger values of inflation corrode personal relationships also, given that there are many financial ties within friends and family.

Inflation messes up information processing
Essence of a market economy is adjustments to relative prices, reflecting changes in tastes and technology. Firms learn about the viability of alternative investments by watching relative prices change. Inflation messes up this information processing. It increases the `background noise’ by making a large number of prices change at once. This makes it harder to discern which price change is fundamentally driven, and merits a response in terms of increased or decreased production.

Impact upon pre-existing nominal savings
For a person at age 60 who expects to live to age 85 or 95, fixed income investments are absolutely crucial in the financial planning of these 25-35 years. These calculations can be destroyed by a short bout of inflation.

Impact upon relationship with banks
When households expect inflation will be 12%, they will see a 4% interest rate paid by the bank as yielding -8%. This has many consequences. On one hand, households and firms expend excessive (wasteful) effort on minimising their holdings of low-yield cash. In addition, they tend to shift away from fixed income contracting with the formal financial system. Both these distortions are caused by inflation, and exacerbated by flaws in the financial system.

These may seem to be small things but they actually are fairly large effects.

But is there not a tradeoff between growth and inflation?
For a brief period, the empirical evidence in the US suggested that there was a tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. Here’s the classic picture, for the 1960s in the US:

Graph shows a nice relationship where higher inflation has gone with lower unemployment. This evidence has led many people, particularly those concerned with the plight of the unemployed, to advocate higher inflation.

A look at the same evidence for the US, over a longer time period, shows no such tradeoff:


The proposition that there is a trade-off between inflation and unemployment was pretty much dead by the late 1970s. One by one, as central banks moved to inflation targeting, aiming and delivering 2% inflation, unemployment went down, not up. Hawkish central banks are the central story about how the stagflation of the 1970s was broken.

There is no tradeoff between inflation and growth. High inflation damages growth and one element of India’s growth crisis is India’s inflation crisis.

It is important to think carefully about the accountability of the central bank. RBI is not in charge of India’s welfare. RBI is in charge of India’s fiat money. The one thing that RBI should be held accountable for is delivering low and stable inflation, i.e. for holding CPI-IW inflation within the 4-5% range.

So that we have seen both the perspectives, it is pretty much clear that high inflation is not a freebie rapped up only in the name of high growth rate. On the same note, the reason identified by Mr. Mohanty held its ground that supply side constraints are the key responsible factor behind this bout of high inflation.

And now, on the solution front, we can’t expect RBI to perform the duties of the Govt. and involve in the state affairs of distribution and supply of the resources. Government, rather than forcing and looking towards RBI to ease interest rates, should do their work sincerely.

All of us are aware of the wastage of the resources; be it rotten grains in the custody of FCI, unused frequency of bandwidth lying with BSNL and MTNL or for that matter line-loss percentage in power transmission. If they can only use these scarce resources effectively and devise a plan and implement the same to bring down the wastage gradually, our Finance Minister, Union of India, would need not to trade the path of growth alone, on the contrary RBI and entire nation would accompany him.

This entry was posted in Uncategorized by admin. Bookmark the permalink.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *